The prevalent view regarding demand management is that is
best achieved through monetary policy -
typically interest rate manipulation - rather than fiscal policy (at least when rates are not at the zero lower bound). There are a
number of aspects to this question, but one of the main objections would have
to be the conflict between short term and long term effects. Monetary policy often works in the short term
by raising debt levels and inflating asset prices, but this can store up problems
for the future.
Those who have worked with SFC models may be familiar with
these dynamics, but they tend to figure less in mainstream constructs. What I have attempted to do here, therefore,
is look at this issue in the context of a simple model with optimising agents
and rational expectations. In addition
to illustrating the problems with an over-reliance on monetary policy, it also brings
out certain dynamics which seem relevant to recent economic trends.
I have based this on a simple model I have used previously
to look at the question of why money has value, which I have extended to
include a government sector. A technical
specification of the model is given at the end of this post.
The economy consists of overlapping generations that live
for two periods, providing a fixed amount of labour in the first and not
working in the second. Households own
land and consume a single consumption good, which is produced by labour alone
with constant returns to scale. Asset
transactions take place at the end of the period. The new generation is born just prior to the
end of the period preceding the one in which they work, enabling them to buy
land from the households that are due to die.
Newborns acquire land by taking out loans. These loans are repaid with interest at the
end of the first period. At this point
households may also buy or sell amounts of land. The balance of funds is held on deposit. Retireds finance their consumption by selling
their land (at the end of the period) and using their deposits.
There is a government that spends in acquiring the
consumption good and that levies taxes on workers. The fiscal rule sets the level of spending
and the rate of tax, which is applied to labour income only. The balance is financed by issuing bonds. Government issued bonds are acquired by
banks, which also make the loans to newborns, in each case by issuing
deposits. The same interest rate is
applied to loans, bonds and deposits.
This rate is set by the monetary authority.
The balance sheet for this economy is shown below. Balances are shown as at the start of each
period. Loans, deposits and bonds are
shown in nominal terms. Land is shown as
a quantity multiplied by a price.
Workers
|
Retireds
|
Banks
|
Government
|
|
Land
|
Aw. Pa
|
Ar. Pa
|
||
Loans
|
-L
|
L
|
||
Deposits
|
D
|
-D
|
||
Bonds
|
B
|
-B
|
The flow of funds in a single period is then shown in the table
below. Repayment of all financial assets
is shown gross of interest. R is equal
to the nominal interest rate plus one.
Newborns
|
Workers
|
Retireds
|
Banks
|
Government
|
|
Consumer spending
|
-Cw . P
|
-Cr . P
|
|||
Government spending
|
-G . P
|
||||
Earnings
|
( G + Cr + Cw ) .
P
|
||||
Taxes
|
-T
|
T
|
|||
Land purchases
|
-Aw . Pa
|
(Awt-1 - Ar)
. Pa
|
Art-1 . Pa
|
||
Loans
|
L
|
- L
|
|||
Loan repayment
|
- Lt-1 . Rt-1
|
Lt-1 . Rt-1
|
|||
Bond issuance
|
- B
|
B
|
|||
Bond redemption
|
Bt-1 . Rt-1
|
- Bt-1 . Rt-1
|
|||
Deposits
|
- D
|
D
|
|||
Deposit repayment
|
Dt-1 . Rt-1
|
- Dt-1 . Rt-1
|
|||
Total
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
Households choose how much to consume in each period and how
much land to hold in each period, subject to their budget constraints.
Starting form a steady state, the particular experiment here
involves a temporary (single period) reduction in government expenditure. It is assumed that this reduction is
unexpected, but that the subsequent reversion to the normal level is expected.
Under perfect price flexibility, with the nominal interest
rate held constant, the level of output can be maintained by a one-off drop in
the price level. This raises the real
value of deposits holdings causing retireds to increase their spending. The fall in the price level also increases
the real debt burden of workers, who respond by reducing their spending but the
effect is less. There is some knock-on
effect due to redistribution between generations, but the economy settles
fairly quickly back to the same (real) steady state values. This is illustrated in the charts below.
What we wish to consider is whether the monetary authority
can use the nominal interest rate to avoid this deflation. This is equivalent to asking whether they can
maintain the level of output even when the price of goods is fixed (but the
price of land is allowed to vary).
The charts below illustrate the outcome where the monetary
authority adjusts the interest rate for ten periods but then holds it stable (the chart for government spending is as above). Compensating for the reduced government
spending requires cutting the interest rate in the first period. This boosts private spending through a wealth
effect. Lower interest rates increase
the price of land, increasing the spending power of those holding it.
However, even when government spending returns to its
baseline value, the interest rate needs to stay low. In boosting private spending, the reduced
interest rate has led to greater private debt and reduced financial savings. This reduces the spending capacity of both
workers and retireds. In fact, in order
to counter this and keep private spending at the original level, the interest
rate has to be reduced again.
As soon as the interest rate is held stable, private
spending drops and output settles at a permanently lower level (but land prices
and debt levels stay at a higher level).
To keep private spending at the level needed to ensure no output gap,
the monetary authority would need to keep cutting the interest rate and inflating
land values indefinitely. It is easy to
see why this must be. In a steady state,
the values of all balances must be constant.
For the level of bonds to be constant, the government's budget must be
balanced, i.e. we need the following equation to hold.
G
. P - T + ( R - 1 ) B = 0
With a given level of output, T is fixed. A fall in G therefore requires a higher level
of ( R - 1 ) B. Cutting the interest
rate reduces R. But it also reduces B,
because B is equal to the net financial position of the private sector. As R falls, households borrow more and also run
down deposits, so B falls. In order to
achieve a steady state, R needs to rise, not fall. But as soon as the monetary authority
increases R, the immediate impact is a fall in output
There is therefore no way (within this model) that the
interest rate can be used to achieve price stability in both goods and land and
a zero output gap, unless fiscal policy adjusts accordingly.
Technical Specification
The number of household in each generation is constant. Each household in the ith generation chooses ci,1, ci,2, ai,1
and ai,2 to maximise expected utility, where c is consumption and a
is holding of land and the second subscripts indicate whether the value is for
the first or second period of life. Labour
is assumed to be supplied in a fixed quantity in the first period of life only. Utility is given by:
(1) Ui
= ( ln ci,1 + φ ln ai,1 ) + β-1 ( ln ci,2
+ φ ln ai,2 )
The budget constraints can be derived from the flow of funds matrix.
(2) q0
ai,1 ≤ li
(3) ci,1 +
q1 ( ai,2 - ai,1 ) + di ≤ wi
- ti - R1 li p0 / p1
(4) ci,2 ≤
q2 ai,2 + R2 di p1
/ p2
where w, t, l and d are wages, taxes,
loans and deposits respectively, all expressed in terms of the consumer
good. R is one plus the nominal interest
rate, p is the price of the consumer good and q is the price of land expressed in
terms of the consumer good. The
subscript for R indicates the period in which the interest is paid.
Production is by labour only and at
constant returns to scale, so competition ensures that the total wages of each
generation are equal to total spending.
(5) wi
=
ci,1 + ci-1,2 + gi
where gi is government spending in the period in
which the ith generation is working,
expressed in terms of the consumer good.
Taxes are a proportion (τi) of wages.
(6) ti
= τi wi
The total amount of available land is fixed.
(7) ai,1 +
ai-1,2 = a*
Parameters for the simulations were: β = 1.50, φ =
0.10. Baseline values were: g = 100, τ =
0.25, R = 1.30, a* = 125. The shock was
a one-period reduction in g to 95.
Initial simulations were constructed over a long period
using steady state solutions as proxy for expected future values. Expected values were then adjusted and the
process repeated until the expectation error was negligible.
[EDIT: After originally posting this, I noticed an error in the model used to generate the graphs. I have corrected this and replaced the graphs. The narrative remains the same.]
[EDIT: After originally posting this, I noticed an error in the model used to generate the graphs. I have corrected this and replaced the graphs. The narrative remains the same.]