I did a
post back in May about manufacturing in the UK and its role in productivity growth and
in foreign trade.
My purpose was to
stress that, for an economy as open as the UK, industry concentration was more about trade than about productivity growth.
The fact is that simply securing productivity growth can actually
be detrimental for a country. The reasons
for this are not immediately obvious, so I drew up a little model to illustrate
it.
There are two countries: Country A and Country B. Each country produces haircuts and one type
of fruit - Country A produces apples and Country B produces bananas. Haircuts are not traded internationally;
fruit is. So households in each country
consume two types of fruit and domestic haircuts.
Wages are fixed in the currency of each country. All prices are set at the same fixed mark-up
to unit labour costs. We'll call Country
A's currency the $, and Country B's £.
The elasticity of substitution in demand is the same for each
product and in each country. We start by
assuming that in both countries, households spend an equal amount on each of
the three products they consume and that 1/3rd of the workforce is employed in producing
haircuts and 2/3rds in producing fruit.
The £ / $ exchange rate floats to ensure that the value of
exports equals the value of imports for each country. The labour supply is fixed and demand is managed to ensure continual
full employment.
So far, each country is identical. The difference we want to introduce is to
suppose that there is a 3% per period growth in labour productivity in the
production of bananas. There is no
change in labour productivity in the production of apples or haircuts.
The charts below are based on an elasticity of substitution in
demand of 0.75 and are normalised to give opening values of unity.
The first thing to notice is that the banana producing Country
B has GDP growth and Country A does not.
(GDP is calculated here as a chained volume measure at opening year
prices.) This is hardly surprising. The GDP
growth rate is less than the rate of growth in banana productivity, because
there is no change in productivity in haircuts.
Rising banana productivity means falling unit labour costs
and falling banana prices in the domestic currency, £.
At the prevailing exchange rate, a fall in the £ banana
price would lead to a drop in the value of exports for Country B, even though
the volume of exports rises, given that the demand elasticity is less than 1. The exchange rate therefore has to change
leading to a fall in the value of the £ against the $. This means that the $ price of bananas falls
by even more than the £ price. It also
means that £ price of apples rises, even though the $ price of apples is
unchanged.
These further price changes alter trade volumes
until the values of trade flows balance. The chart below shows that this involves a big increase in the banana exports of Country B, whilst there is a slight decline in Country A's apple exports. This is consistent with Thirlwall's Law and what is happening here to GDP.
The exchange rate movement also means that consumer prices fall by more in Country A than in Country B. This means that real wages (based on a consumption price index - not the GDP deflator) rise more slowly in Country B than in
Country A, notwithstanding that Country B is generating all of the growth in
production.
In this model, Country A wages rise faster than those in
Country B whenever the elasticity of substitution in demand is less than 1. In fact, if the elasticity is less than about
0.61, then real wages in Country B actually fall, because the £ price of apples
rises faster than the £ price of bananas falls.
This result is somewhat counter-intuitive.
These elasticity levels are not at all unrealistic for
international trade flows.
As a further point it is worth noting that Country B can
mitigate the reduction in its own real wages by depressing domestic demand. This reduces employment and GDP in Country B. It raises real wages in Country B, but
reduces them in Country A. Imposing
tariffs (whether on exports or on imports) will also raise real wages in
Country B at the expense of those in Country A, but does not involve reduced
employment.
The purpose of this post is simply to highlight two points:
1. GDP growth is not the same as growth in living standards.
A country that has a high proportion of
activity in industries with strong productivity growth is likely to have high
GDP growth. But this, in itself, is not
a good reason to concentrate on such industries.
2. Elasticities in traded goods are crucial.
However, it is not the purpose of this post to suggest that it is a
bad thing to have industries with high potential productivity growth. In practice growth in productivity is not mainly
about producing more of the same for given inputs; it is about producing new
and better products. This innovation is itself
important in developing and sustaining export demand. We cannot separate developments in trade from
what is happening with productivity growth.
The important point though is that trade is a critical part of the
picture; productivity growth alone tells us very little.
Equation Listing
Consumption of each good in each country is based on a consumption index
and the price relative to a consumption price index.
1. CAa
= CA / 3 . (p$a / pA)-ε
2. CAb
= CA / 3 . (p$b / pA)-ε
3. CAh
= CA / 3 . (p$h / pA)-ε
4. CBa
= CB / 3 . ( p£a / pB)-ε
5. CBb
= CB / 3 . (p£b / pB)-ε
6. CBh
= CB / 3 . (p£h / pB)-ε
With the price indices calculated as:
7. pA
= ( p$a . CAa + p$b . CAb + p$h
. CAh) / CA
8. pB
= ( p£a . CBa + p£b . CBb + p£h
. CBh) / CB
All domestic prices are set at the same mark-up to unit
labour costs.
9. p£b
= λ
. wB / σb
10. p£h
= λ
. wB / σh
11. p$a
= λ
. wA / σa
12. p$h
= λ
. wA / σh
Import prices reflect the exchange rate.
13. p£a
= e
. p$a
14. p$b
= p£b / e
The value of exports equals the value of imports. (This equation is used to find the market
clearing exchange rate.)
15. CAb
. p$b = CBa . p$a
Employment is based on consumption and productivity. (In the basic scenario described, the
levels of the consumption indices CA and CB are set so that all available labour is employed in both countries.)
16. LB
= CBh / σh + ( CAb + CBb ) / σb
17. LA
= CAh / σh + ( CAa + CBa ) / σa
Variables
CXy Consumption
of y in country X
CX Consumption
index in country X
pzy Price
of y denominated in z
pX Price
index in country X, denominated in domestic currency
wX Nominal
wages in country X, denominated in domestic currency
σy Labour
productivity in production of y
LX Employment
in country X
e Exchange
rate ( £ per $ )
σ is given the same value for each good, in the first period.