An interesting point came up in my recent discussion with
Stephen Williamson (referred to in my last post, but there's no need to read
that to understand what I'm going to say here.)
It is to do with the interpretation of Ricardian Equivalence, when there
are unexpected policy changes. I
actually thought the point was obvious, but from Williamson's response I am
left thinking that it's either not obvious or I'm wrong. If anyone wishes to enlighten me either way,
I'd be grateful.
To look at this, I need to make some of the standard
assumptions for Ricardian Equivalence to apply, so I'm going to assume homogenous
households with infinite horizons and no issues like liquidity constraints. Under this assumption, the long-run government
budget constraint is binding. This says
that the present value of taxes cannot be less than the value of current debt
plus the present value of government spending.
The usual way to interpret this is to suppose that any
change in tax now must be offset by a change in tax at some future time. So, for example, if there is a one-off tax
reduction today, then this will need to be financed by issuing debt. That additional debt, plus the interest, must
be repaid at some point and this requires future taxes.
This analysis is usually set out in real (non-monetary)
terms, with bonds paying a real rate of interest.
In this case, there is no way other than a future tax increase for the
government budget constraint to be met.
However, in reality, public debt is generally issued in
nominal terms, paying a nominal rate of interest. This means that the actual rate of return
will vary from the expected rate of return if there is unexpected
inflation. What matters for the
government's budget constraint is the actual rate of return.
So, consider a case where the government makes an unexpected
tax cut. One possibility we have to
consider is that this will lead to a higher inflation than was expected before
the tax cut was known about. The result
would be that the actual rate of return on outstanding government debt is lower
than previously expected. This
represents a kind of unexpected inflation tax on bondholders, which must be
factored into the government budget constraint.
The need for future taxes is correspondingly lower.
In a model with perfectly flexible prices, we might have a
position where an immediate jump in the price level produces an inflation tax
that completely offsets the impact of the tax reduction. In this case, the tax reduction would have no
impact, simply because it would make no net difference to households' real position. The Ricardian Equivalence result holds,
albeit somewhat trivially.
With sticky prices, it's a different matter. Any inflation shock that occurs in response
to a tax reduction must be correlated with inflation in subsequent periods,
whether under a forward-looking or backward-looking relationship. So, if a current tax reduction is to be
recouped through an inflation tax, that must take place over time. And, throughout the period of higher inflation,
expected real interest rates are higher, which will impact on the pattern of
household spending. So, in this case,
the choice between taxation or bond issuance does make a difference.
It needs to be stressed that this is fully consistent with
rational expectations, provided we are considering an unexpected change in
taxation (or equivalently a change in actual taxation, following a known rule,
but in response to some other unexpected event). The standard New Keynesian Phillips curve has
current inflation as a function of expected inflation. We can equate expected inflation to the
actual outcome for every point in time where there are no unexpected tax policy
changes. But, if a new policy is
announced we have to allow for expectations to be revised accordingly.
In a standard New Keynesian model, therefore, we seem to
have two options as to how an unexpected tax reduction might play out:
We can assume that people do not revise their inflation expectations and that they believe that the government will
increase taxes again in the future to pay off (with interest) the debt incurred
to finance the tax cut. In this case,
the model-consistent expectation solution is that there is no inflation shock,
and indeed the only way the government budget constraint can be met is by
increased future taxes.
Alternatively, we can
assume that people do not believe that the government will raise future taxes and that they revise their inflation expectations to take this into account. In this case, the model-consistent expectation
solution is an (unexpected) jump in inflation, followed by a steady fall in
inflation back to its baseline level. This
inflation erodes the value of outstanding debt and the government budget
constraint is indeed met without any future taxes.
If we were using a non-monetary model, we would have no choice but to go the first route, because there is no unexpected inflation. But once we think in terms of monetary debts, there is no good reason for saying that the former should hold rather than the latter. The first gives us the classic Ricardian Equivalence result; the second does not.
The path of output, inflation and (nominal) interest rate in this second case would be something like that shown below (model details at end of post). The shock occurs when the announcement is made. It makes no difference whether the tax reduction is actually applied now or in the future. In that sense, the result is still Ricardian.
If we were using a non-monetary model, we would have no choice but to go the first route, because there is no unexpected inflation. But once we think in terms of monetary debts, there is no good reason for saying that the former should hold rather than the latter. The first gives us the classic Ricardian Equivalence result; the second does not.
The path of output, inflation and (nominal) interest rate in this second case would be something like that shown below (model details at end of post). The shock occurs when the announcement is made. It makes no difference whether the tax reduction is actually applied now or in the future. In that sense, the result is still Ricardian.
A key point here is we are relying on the fact that, under
the government budget constraint, a current tax reduction can be made whole either
by an increase in future taxes or by a change in the rate at which future taxes
are discounted. The usual approach is to
assume that there needs to be a rise in futures taxes. This leads to a self-fulfilling loop:
a) Because there is an offsetting rise in future taxes,
there is no change in household spending and real interest rates remain unchanged.
b) Because real interest rates remain unchanged, there needs
to be a increase in future taxes to meet the government budget constraint.
The trick is to recognise that when we have expectation
shocks and sticky prices, there is an alternative:
a) Because there is no offsetting rise in future taxes, households
spend more currently, causing a temporary, but drawn out, reduction in real
interest rates.
b) Because of the reduction in future real interest rates,
the present value of future taxes is increased and so there is no need for
additional taxes to meet the government budget constraint.
In my view, this is actually quite an important point of
departure between mainstream and more heterodox approaches. If we come at this from a mindset that sees
the government budget constraint as something that dictates policy, rather than
simply an accounting identity, then we might naturally assume the former. But, if we take the view that the government
will just do what it thinks appropriate from time to time and we just need to
work out how the economy responds, then we might be more inclined to the
latter. And, in my opinion, the latter
is more plausible.
Model
The model I've used here is a standard three equation NK
model with an additional equation showing the evolution of the government debt
and the further condition that the level of debt is bounded (this is equivalent
to the government budget constraint).
(1) yt = E[yt+1] . (
β . it+1 / E[πt+1] )-σ
(2) πt = E[πt+1]β
. ytκ
(3) it+1 = i* + φπ .
( E[πt+1] - 1 ) + φy . ( E[yt+1] - 1 )
(4) bt = bt-1 . it
/ πt - τt
where y is output, π is inflation (both normalised to 1), i
is the nominal interest rate, τ is tax and b is the real value of government debt. Parameter values used are β = 0.97, σ = 1, κ
= 0.2, φπ = 0.5, φy = 0.4 and i* is set at 1/β. The baseline level of tax is 0.2 and the shock is a one-off reduction by 0.05.
The usual approach would be to take equation (4) and the
boundary condition simply to place a constraint on the level of taxes, in which
case it has no bearing on the other variables.
What we are doing here is allowing taxes to be freely set, letting
expectations adjust when a change in tax policy is announced and using equation
(4), plus the boundary condition, to pin those expectations down.