I've talked quite a bit recently about overlapping generation
models, in particular Samuelson. I
thought it would be useful to put Samuelson's model into some simple
illustrations, because I believe the process by which it creates a functional relationship
between income and wealth is a very important one.
In this model, agents live for three periods. They work and earn for the first two periods,
but do not work for the third. They
spread their spending however, so that in the first two periods they are spending
less than they earn and are therefore saving, which they do by acquiring assets.
In the last period, they realise their savings and use the proceeds to fund their spending. The life
cycle of each agent is shown below.
Some accounting identities are being used here. Saving is the difference between income and
spending. Saving or dis-saving then
changes the balance of assets held. The
value of assets may also be affected by changes in the price; the older
generation may find it can sell the assets for more than it paid for them. More on this later.
After the third period, each agent "dies" but a
new generation is born to repeat the process.
There is therefore a constant chain of newer generations saving and
older generations dis-saving. It is useful in this
model to think of savings as being held in the form of some kind of financial
instrument, in fixed supply. We
therefore have a permanent market where the younger generations (1&2) are
buying assets to facilitate their saving, and the older generation (3) is selling
them. This is shown below:
We have said nothing about how agents spread their
spending. The chart suggests they are
spending equally in each period, but this need not be so. They may wish to spend more earlier in life
or even to defer spending. This will
change the numbers slightly, but the overall pattern will stay the same. We will still get a position whereby each
generation accumulates wealth and then runs it down. Furthermore, if the time preferences do not
change and aggregate income stays the same then the aggregate balance of assets
will stay the same. Each individual's
balance rises then falls, but the saving cancels out the dis-saving.
The market for assets consists then of younger generations
as buyers and older generations as sellers.
This is where Samuelson's results come from. In his simple case, with no growth, the
number of buyers and sellers is the same from one period to the next, so the
price of assets stays constant. However, if we
have a situation where each new generation is larger than the last, the number
of buyers is growing and the value of assets must rise. With the quantity of assets in fixed supply,
the price must grow in line with the population in order to be able to fulfill
the growing demand for savings. This
growth in price creates a yield on the asset - Samuelson's rate of interest.
Samuelson's result should be viewed with caution. For the interest rate to be equal to the growth rate requires
that there is no outside sectors (government or overseas) and that there is no
internal transfer element to the return on assets. However, I do believe that the idea of viewing
the demand for assets as a function of a natural life-cycle and a trade between
different generations gives us important insights into things we see in the
real world.
One of the things you can do with the OLG models is get a handle on how wealth and spending inter-relate under the assumption of rationality. You could then try to fit this behaviour with a simple function that you can then use inside a Stock-Flow Consistent model. You end up with a hybrid model, with DSGE elements, but it is a model that you can actually solve.
ReplyDeleteYes. The OLG pattern of behaviour does of course produce a spending pattern quite similar to that in standard SFC models, but because it is also a type of micro-founded approach, you can incorporate rationality assumptions and utility maximisation, if you wish. Sometimes it's instructive to do so and I have actually done quite a bit of playing around with models like that. The most interesting thing that comes out of it, to my mind, is that the results are still very different to those of the standard NK model.
DeleteI saw your recent post on Ricardian Equivalence and it's worth noting as well that the possibility that at least some households are acting like OLG agents is another reason why RE won't hold.
Yes, sensible behavioural assumptions puts RE into doubt. The behaviour at infinity is another issue. It's less cut and dried than the problem with the term premium, and so I will have to think about how to explain it properly.
DeleteNick, I can't remember whether I previously mentioned this link on comments here:
ReplyDeleteWhy Do the Rich Save So Much?
Christopher D. Carroll
http://www.econ2.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll/why.pdf
It finds that a sizable chunk of assets are held by people with a "capitalist spirit" motivation -that is they NEVER intend for those assets to be dissaved either by them or their heirs. That kind of throws a spanner in the works because the yield from those assets causes more and more to be gathered.
I also worry that calls for population growth and migrations are actually motivated by the wish to inflate asset prices. The motivation is to benefit current holders of wealth at the expense of those who don't (yet) hold wealth.
I had a go trying to get to grips with this in a couple of posts
http://directeconomicdemocracy.wordpress.com/2013/07/28/demographics-migration-and-fiscal-sustainability/
http://directeconomicdemocracy.wordpress.com/2013/06/09/sustainability-of-economic-growth-and-debt/
Hi Stone,
DeleteYou did mention it before and I think it's important. I'm not trying to argue here that this OLG pattern is a complete description of how households behave. I don't think it is. However, I do think it represents the way a material part of behaviour and that has important consequences, particularly that many of the conclusions based on agents with infinite horizons break down. The type of behaviour you describe is also, of course, not consistent with the standard representative agent. But it also means, as you say, that this type of OLG model is not enough to describe everything that is going on.