The UK's
decision to quit the EU has left a lot of uncertainty over its future trading
position. It will probably be a long
time before it becomes clear what kind of arrangements can be
negotiated, but the concern is that the UK could suffer damage to
export capability, with little reduction in its susceptibility to import penetration.
One immediate
consequence of these concerns has been a sharp fall in sterling. In principle, this should be good news for UK
export capability, and there was a case to be made that sterling was overvalued
before the referendum. However, if this
indeed reflects a weakened trade position, then assessing the overall impact is
more tricky.
As such,
I thought it would be interesting to use a stock-flow consistent model to look
at how a shock to export capability and consequent exchange rate weakening might
impact on overall activity.
The model
I have used here is essentially the same as one described in an earlier
post. It is purely conceptual - no
attempt has been made to calibrate it to the UK. The main difference compared to the earlier
version is that I have expanded on the way inflation is determined. The mechanism here
is based on real wage targeting and follows that used in Godley & Lavoie (p
302), incorporating adaptive inflation expectations. Pricing is a straightforward mark-up to unit labour
costs.
Otherwise,
the only real departure from what might be found in Godley and Lavoie is the
use of forward looking expectations for the exchange rate. This is useful here, where we want to look at
the impact of a change in expectations of future trade prospects.
As usual,
I have provided a full equation listing at the end of the post.
The
graphs below show the effect on selected variables of a 5% fall in the base
level of exports (i.e. before taking account of changes due to relative price).
One of
the first things to note is that although this leads to a fall in actual real exports,
there is a much greater fall in real imports.
This is due to the fall in the real exchange rate. Exports become cheaper which mitigates the
impact of the change in the base level of demand. However, this worsening in the terms of trade
means that the level of foreign earnings from exporting has fallen
dramatically. The amount of imports this
buys has been significantly reduced.
In
itself, the fact that import volumes have fallen by more than export volumes
might be expected to provide a boost to domestic production. However, the worsening of the terms of trade reduces
the real value of domestic income, specifically when we measure by reference to
the consumer price deflator rather than the GDP deflator. Consider what happens to the real wage as
shown in the graph. The nominal wage deflated
by the price of domestic output is a constant, because of the mark-up
pricing. But, because consumption also
includes imports, when the real wage is deflated by the consumer price index it
closely reflects changes in the real exchange rate.
This
erosion in the value of real income reduces consumer expenditure and this is
enough to more than outweigh the boost to output from reduced imports.
Although
the scale of this depends on the parameters, the direction of change is a
consequence of the stock-flow structure.
In a model like this, GDP tends towards a level which achieves a steady
state level of government debt. This is
largely determined by the fiscal stance.
However, inflation will have an impact because it erodes the real value
of the government debt.
The
decline in the real exchange rate gives an inflationary impulse. Eventually, this settles down to a higher
level of inflation giving a reduced real return on domestic assets compared
with overseas assets. This is necessary
because, when valued in the same currency, the fall in the real exchange rate has made the supply of domestic assets lower relative to the supply of foreign assets. (It is, of course, possible that seperate factors might also impact on the relative demand for these assets. This is not considered here, but is obviously relevant in the context of the fallout from the Brexit vote.)
The
higher level of inflation can be seen in graph.
This erodes government debt, requiring the state to run a slightly
higher deficit to compensate. This
higher deficit implies lower tax revenues, which in turn implies a lower level
of GDP.
Equation Listing
Equations
(1) to (15) are as described in the previous model.
(1) y =
d + g + x
(2) d = ( C - m . pf / e ) / p
(3) C = α1 . YD + α2 . ( Bd-1 + Fd-1
/ e )
(4) YD = y . p - T + r-1 . BD-1
+ rf . Fd-1 / e
(5) T = τ .
( y . p + r-1 . Bd-1 + rf . Fd-1 / e )
(6) m = d . µ . ( e . p / pf )σ1
(7) x = x0 . ( e . p / pf )σ2
(8) V = YD - C + Bd-1 + Fd-1
/ e
(9) Fd = e . λ1 . V. ( rrf / r )κ1
(10) Bw = λ2 . Vf / e . ( rrd / rf )κ2
(11) B = B-1 . ( 1 +r-1 )
+ g . p - T
(12) Bd = V - Fd / e
(13) Bw = B - Bd
(14) rrd = ( 1 + rd ) . E[ e+1 ] / e
- 1
(15) rrf = ( 1 + rf ) . e / E[ e+1 ]
- 1
Employment
is proportional to output.
(16) n = φ . y
The target
real wage is based on the level of employment.
(17) wrt = wrt0 . ( n / n0
)δ
Nominal
wage adjustment is based on inflation expectations and the gap between the
target real wage and the previous actual real wage.
(18) w = w-1 . E[π] . ( wrt . pc-1
/ w-1 )ψ
Prices
are a straight mark-up to unit labour costs.
(19) p = β . w . n / y
Consumer
prices are approximated as the deflator between nominal consumer spending and
an aggregate volume measure.
(20) pc = C / ( d + m )
Inflation
expectations are adaptive.
(21) E[π] = E[π]-1 + ε . ( π-1
- E[π]-1 )
Where
inflation is taken as the change in consumer prices (expressed as 1 plus the
change).
(22) π = pc / pc-1
Variables
The
variables are listed below. Uppercase
variables denote nominal values.
B
|
Domestic
bonds
|
Bd
|
Domestic
bonds held by domestic investors
|
Bw
|
Domestic
bonds held by overseas investors
|
d
|
Domestic
expenditure by the domestic private sector
|
e
|
Exchange
rate (units of foreign currency per unit of domestic currency)
|
Fd
|
Overseas
bonds held by domestic investors (in foreign currency terms)
|
g
|
Real
government expenditure
|
m
|
Real
imports
|
n
|
Employment
|
n0
|
Base
level of employment
|
p
|
Price
of domestic output
|
pc
|
Consumer
price deflator
|
pf
|
Price
of foreign output
|
r
|
Interest
rate on domestic bonds
|
rf
|
Interest
rate on foreign bonds
|
rrd
|
Expected
return to foreign investors on domestic bonds
|
rrf
|
Expected
return to domestic investors on foreign bonds
|
T
|
Taxes
|
V
|
Net
financial wealth of domestic private sector
|
Vf
|
Financial
wealth of rest of world (in foreign currency terms)
|
w
|
Nominal
wage
|
wrt
|
Target
real wage
|
wrt0
|
Base
level of target real wage
|
x
|
Real
exports
|
x0
|
Base
level of real exports
|
y
|
Real
output
|
YD
|
Disposable
income of domestic private sector
|
π
|
Consumer
price inflation
|
Policy
variables are the level of government expenditure, the tax rate (τ) and the
domestic interest rate. Foreign
variables (Vf, x0 and rf) are taken as exogenous in accordance with
the "small" economy assumption. E[ ] denotes the expected value of a variable. Expected values of exchange rates are set equal to actual outcomes, except for the period of the shock.
No comments:
Post a Comment